contents

Macroeconomics

Overview of Macroeconomics

Macroeconomic Indicators

The Connection between Indicators

Central Bank Policy

Global Economic Context

Learning Goals for the Course

Conclusion

This introductory lecture aims to provide a foundational understanding of macroeconomics, its core concepts, and the significance of macroeconomic indicators in the context of a dynamic global economy. The subsequent lectures will delve deeper into these topics with a focus on definitions and models essential for macroeconomic analysis.

Macroeconomic Concepts and Definitions

Introduction

Defining Aggregate Output

What is Output?

National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA)

Measures of GDP

Understanding GDP

GDP is the total value of all final goods and services produced in an economy over a specified period.

Methods to Calculate GDP

Three methods:

  1. Final Goods Approach:
    GDP = Value of Final Goods and Services

  2. Value Added Approach:
    Value Added = Final Goods Value − Intermediate Inputs Cost

  3. Income Approach:
    GDP = Wages + Profits

Nominal GDP vs. Real GDP

Nominal GDP

Real GDP

GDP Growth Comparison

Unemployment Metrics

Defining Employment and Unemployment

Inflation

Understanding Inflation

Price Levels and Indices

Macroeconomics: Introduction to Aggregate Demand

Introduction

Understanding the potential for a recession is fundamental in macroeconomics. A recession typically refers to a decline in aggregate output, which can be observed through surveys conducted on economists. These economists are often tasked with assessing the probability of recession within a specified timeframe (in this case, 12 months). The prevailing sentiment regarding economic downturns illustrates a significant reliance on models that determine equilibrium output.

Course Overview

Throughout this course, we will explore various models that illustrate how output is determined in different time frames:

Aggregate Demand Components

Aggregate demand (Z) is composed of the following elements:

The equation for aggregate demand in a closed economy (disregarding X and IM) can be expressed as:
Z = C + I + G

For the purposes of this course:
Z = C + 0 + G  (Assuming investment and government spending are constants)

Defining Consumption

Consumption is defined as an increasing function of disposable income. The function capturing consumption can be expressed as:
C = C0 + C1(Y − T)
where:

It is crucial to note that C1 (MPC) is valued between 0 and 1; as income increases, consumption increases at a diminishing rate.

Equilibrium Output

The equilibrium output in an economy is determined at the point where aggregate demand equals total output:
Y = Z
Inserting the expression for aggregate demand provides:
Y = C0 + C1(Y − T) + G

Rearranging this yields the fundamental equation for equilibrium output:
$$Y = \frac{C_0 + G + C_1 T}{1 - C_1}$$

This formula highlights the multiplier effect, which is defined as:
$$\text{Multiplier} = \frac{1}{1 - C_1}$$
The multiplier serves to amplify the effects of changes in consumption, government spending, or taxes on overall output.

The Multiplier’s Role

The size of the multiplier indicates the effectiveness of fiscal policies. Higher values of C1 enhance the multiplier, leading to a more significant increase in equilibrium output following a change in expenditures.

Shifts in Aggregate Demand

Consider the scenario where C0 (autonomous consumption) increases:

Subsequent iterations of increased income from the initial consumption will further increase demand, showcasing the multiplier effect in action.

The Paradox of Savings

While saving is generally encouraged, an increase in overall savings can paradoxically lead to a decrease in equilibrium output when measured macroeconomically. This can occur due to the multiplier effect:

  1. Higher saving decreases consumption for any given level of income.

  2. As consumption falls, demand decreases, leading to lower output.

  3. Ultimately, lower output results in less income, which further decreases consumption.

This insight underscores the complexity of macroeconomic dynamics compared to microeconomic theories.

Conclusion

In summary, this lecture has introduced the foundational concepts of aggregate demand, the nature of consumption, and the mechanics behind equilibrium output. The intricacies of the multiplier effect and the potential paradox of increased savings highlight how interconnected macroeconomic factors can be. Understanding these principles is vital as we delve deeper into macroeconomic analysis in upcoming lectures.

Understanding Interest Rates and Monetary Policy

Introduction

This lecture addresses the determination of interest rates, particularly in the context of monetary policy and financial markets. The discussion pertains to the aggressive monetary policies implemented by central banks, specifically the United States Federal Reserve (Fed), to combat inflation.

Monetary Policy and Interest Rates

Central Banks and Their Role

Central banks, such as the Federal Reserve in the US and the Bank of Japan, play a crucial role in setting interest rates. The current chair of the Federal Reserve is Jerome Powell.

Key Concepts

  1. Interest Rates: The rates at which interest is paid by borrowers for the use of money they borrow from lenders.

  2. Monetary Policy: A tool used by central banks to influence the economy by controlling the money supply and interest rates.

Instruments of Monetary Policy

The relationship between money demand (Md) and the interest rate (r) can be described as follows:


Md = Md(r, Y)

where Y is nominal income, and the demand for money decreases as the interest rate increases (downward sloping curve).

Money Demand and Supply

Demand for Money

The demand for money can be affected by: 1. Interest rate changes. 2. Shifts in nominal income.

Equilibrium Interest Rate

The equilibrium interest rate occurs where money demand equals money supply, depicted by the equation:


Md = Ms

where Ms is the money supply determined by the central bank.

In case the central bank increases the money supply, the equilibrium interest rate will fall as shown:


If Ms ↓  → r

Impact of Monetary Policy Changes

Intermediate Effects and Financial Markets

In practice, central banks conduct operations through:

Open Market Operations

Interest Rate and Bond Price Relationship

The relationship between bond prices (PB) and interest rates (r) is inversely related. The interest rate of a bond can be expressed as:


$$r = \frac{C}{P_B}$$

where C is the cash flow received from the bond (e.g., payoff at maturity).

Market for Reserves and Federal Funds Rate

The market for reserves is essential for understanding how central banks implement monetary policy. The Federal Reserve targets the Federal Funds Rate, the rate at which banks lend reserves to each other overnight.

Demand for Reserves

The demand for reserves can be expressed as:


Hd = θMd

where θ is the required reserve ratio.

Interest Rate Control

The central bank influences the interest rate through the supply of reserves (H):


Hs = monetary policy actions

If demand for reserves exceeds supply, the interest rate will rise:


r ↑  if Hd > Hs

Conclusion

The lecture concludes by reiterating the roles of central banks in influencing interest rates through monetary policy. The practices have evolved with an understanding of the complexities of financial markets today.

Detailed Notes on the IS-LM Model and U.S. Economic State

Overview of the U.S. Economy

Before delving into the IS-LM model, let’s examine the current state of the U.S. economy and its impact on aggregate demand.

Household wealth, composed primarily of net worth, shows a general upward trend, with notable declines during recessions, including the COVID-19 recession. However, post-recession, there has been a significant recovery in asset prices, including:

Despite the downturn in 2022, the overall wealth increase is notable. Increased household wealth typically leads to increased consumption and hence higher aggregate demand.

Factors Contributing to Increases in Wealth

  1. Asset Prices: Rapid increases in stock and real estate prices contribute significantly to wealth.

  2. Government Transfers: Large governmental monetary transfers helped maintain incomes, particularly for lower-income households during COVID-19, leading to increased savings.

Personal Savings Rate

Understanding Aggregate Demand

Aggregate demand is influenced by both consumer wealth and spending behavior. The relationship can be summarized as:
AD ∝ C + I + G + NX
Where AD is aggregate demand, C is consumption, I is investment, G is government spending, and NX is net exports.

The IS-LM Model

The IS-LM model combines the goods market (IS) and money market (LM) to find equilibrium output and interest rate.

IS Relation

The IS curve represents the equilibrium in the goods market:

LM Relation

The LM curve represents the equilibrium in the money market:

Equilibrium in the IS-LM Model

The intersection of the IS and LM curves determines the equilibrium levels of output (Y*) and interest rate (i*).

Shifts in the IS-LM Curves

Adjustment to Changes

When the IS curve shifts due to fiscal policy changes:


Y′ < Y


Y′ > Y

Conclusion

The IS-LM model provides a foundational understanding of how output and interest rates are determined in an economy influenced by fiscal and monetary policies. It allows for deeper analysis of the impacts of various shocks and government interventions, particularly in a complex environment like the post-COVID U.S. economy.

IS-LM Model Notes

Introduction to IS-LM Model

The IS-LM model is a foundational concept in macroeconomics, illustrating the interaction between the goods market (IS) and the money market (LM). This model helps analyze economic policy responses, particularly during shocks such as the COVID-19 pandemic.

IS Curve

Construction of the IS Curve

The IS curve represents the combinations of output (Y) and interest rate (i) that satisfy equilibrium in the goods market. The following components contribute to the IS relation:

The IS curve is downward sloping because higher interest rates reduce investment and hence total demand (Y).

Equilibrium in the Goods Market

Equilibrium is achieved when:
Y = C(Y − T) + I + G + NX
Where:

Shifts and Movements Along the IS Curve

LM Curve

Construction of the LM Curve

The LM curve reflects equilibrium in the money market, where real money supply equals real money demand:
$$\frac{M}{P} = L(Y, i)$$
Where:

Assuming P is constant in the short run leads to:
M = L(Y, i)

The LM curve is typically upward sloping, indicating that as output (Y) increases, the interest rate (i) must rise to maintain money market equilibrium.

Modern Monetary Policy

In the current context, central banks set interest rates directly rather than targeting money supply. This results in a flat LM curve at the target interest rate set by the central bank.

Equilibrium Output

Combining the IS and LM curves allows the determination of equilibrium output: - The point at which both curves intersect signifies the equilibrium interest rate and output level (Y*, i*).
Equilibrium: (Y*, i*)

Macroeconomic Policy Response

Fiscal Policy

Fiscal policy can be expansionary or contractionary:

Monetary Policy

Monetary policy involves changes in the interest rate, affecting investment:

The Multiplier Effect

The multiplier effect amplifies the impact of changes in spending:
$$\text{Final Output Change} = \frac{1}{1 - MPC} \cdot \Delta G$$
Where is the marginal propensity to consume, and ΔG is the change in government spending.

Liquidity Trap

When the nominal interest rate is effectively zero, monetary policy becomes ineffective, known as the liquidity trap:

Case Study: COVID-19 Economic Response

During the COVID-19 pandemic:

Conclusion

The IS-LM model provides insights into how various macroeconomic policies affect equilibrium output and interest rates. Understanding the interactions between fiscal and monetary policy is vital for effective economic management, especially during periods of economic shock.

Lecture Notes: Extensions to the IS-LM Model

Introduction

The IS-LM model is foundational in macroeconomics and provides insight into the interactions between the goods market (IS) and the money market (LM). This lecture will extend the IS-LM model in two key dimensions: the distinction between nominal and real interest rates, and the incorporation of credit spreads in corporate borrowing.

Nominal vs. Real Interest Rates

Definitions

Why Real Interest Rates Matter

The real interest rate influences significant investment decisions in the private sector. For durable goods consumer purchases and physical investment, it is the real rate, not the nominal rate, that matters because it represents the opportunity cost of investment adjusted for inflation.

Derivation of the Real Interest Rate

To derive the real interest rate, we equate the returns from nominal bonds and real goods:
$$1 + r = (1 + i) \frac{P_t}{P_{t+1}}^e$$
From this, we can rearrange to express it in terms of expected inflation:
r ≈ i − πe

Impact of Inflation and Credit Spreads on the IS-LM Model

Credit Spreads

Most corporate bonds are considered risky. The interest rate on these bonds can be represented as:
rf = r + xt
where xt is the risk premium reflecting the higher borrowing costs associated with corporate lending compared to treasuries.

Risk Premium Dynamics

The risk premium, xt, increases in response to:

During recessions, both factors can amplify, causing a significant increase in the credit spread.

Modifications to the IS-LM Model

The modifications include: 1. Replacing the nominal interest rate in the investment function with the real interest rate adjusted by credit risk:
I = f(r − xt, Y)

Shifts in the ZZ Curve

An increase in expected inflation (π) or a decrease in credit spreads (xt) will shift the ZZ curve upwards, mimicking the effects of expansionary monetary policy:
ΔY = f(Δπ,  − Δxt)

Conversely, during financial crises: Increases in the risk premium and declines in expected inflation shift the ZZ curve downwards.

Recent Economic Context

Conclusion

Understanding the dynamics between nominal and real interest rates and the implications of credit spreads is crucial for effective investment decisions and policy formulation. The IS-LM model, while foundational, requires these extensions to accurately reflect contemporary economic conditions.

Notes on Labor Market and Wage Determination

Introduction to the Labor Market

The labor market plays a critical role in macroeconomics due to its influence on key indicators such as:

Labor Market Statistics

As of recent data, the following statistics illustrate the labor market dynamics:

The unemployment rate is calculated as:
$$\text{Unemployment Rate} = \frac{\text{Number of Unemployed}}{\text{Civilian Labor Force}} \times 100$$

Dynamic Nature of Labor Markets

Labor markets exhibit large monthly flows amid static stock statistics:

Wage Determination

Wage determination can be influenced by several factors:

The concept of the reservation wage, which is the minimum wage level at which a worker would prefer to be employed rather than unemployed, is crucial. Workers typically demand wages above their reservation wages for various economic and psychological reasons.

Wage Setting Equation

Wages can be represented as an increasing function of the expected price level and decreasing function of unemployment. Mathematically, we can express this as:
W = f(Pe, U, z)
where:

Price Setting Equation

The price that firms are willing to charge can be represented by:
P = (1 + M)W
Here:

Thus, the real wage offered by the firm can be expressed as:
$$W_r = \frac{W}{P} = \frac{W}{(1 + M)W} = \frac{1}{1 + M}$$

Natural Rate of Unemployment

The natural rate of unemployment (Un) reflects labor market conditions where expected prices equal actual prices:
Un occurs when Pe = P
The relationship between the unemployment rate, price expectations, and wages can be shown graphically, where the intersection of the wage-setting and price-setting equations determines the natural rate of unemployment.

Effects of Changes in z and M

1. Increase in Bargaining Power z:

2. Increase in Markup M:

Conclusion

These foundational concepts illustrate the interplay between labor market dynamics, wage setting, and macroeconomic variables such as inflation and unemployment. The next step involves examining the Phillips Curve to understand how deviations between expected and actual prices influence inflation.

Lecture Notes: Phillips Curve and Inflation

Introduction

In today’s lecture, we will explore the Phillips curve and its relationship to inflation. The Phillips curve represents a central concept in macroeconomics, particularly its implications on the relationship between unemployment and inflation. This will extend beyond mere empirical analysis to theoretical underpinning using established economic models.

Understanding the Phillips Curve

Historical Context

The Phillips curve was first introduced by economist A.W. Phillips in 1958, where he observed a negative correlation between unemployment rates and inflation in the United States from historical data. This empirical relationship was later popularized by Paul Samuelson and Robert Solow.

Mathematical Representation

The Phillips curve is commonly visualized as a downward-sloping curve. That is:
If U (unemployment) decreases, then π (inflation) increases.

Wage Setting and Price Setting

We start with two key equations from the previous lectures:

1. Wage Setting Equation:
W = F(u, z)
where W is the nominal wage, u the unemployment rate, and z represents labor market institutions (increasing function).

2. Price Setting Equation:
P = (1 + m)W
where P is the price level and m is a markup.

The wage-setting equation reflects that as unemployment u rises, wage demand W decreases, and as z increases, wage demand increases.

Deriving the Phillips Curve

Starting with the relationship between inflation and the price level:
$$\pi = \frac{P_t - P_{t-1}}{P_{t-1}} = \frac{P_t}{P_{t-1}} - 1$$
Rearranging this in terms of expected inflation gives:
Pt = (1 + πe)Pt − 1
where πe is expected inflation.

Substituting in both the wage and price equations ultimately leads us to the relation:
π = πe − α(u − un)
where un is the natural rate of unemployment, a key concept in understanding inflation dynamics.

Natural Rate of Unemployment

The natural rate of unemployment un satisfies the conditions where expected inflation equals actual inflation. Mathematically:
un = F − 1(π, z)
This means that higher z or m leads to an increase in un due to changes in bargaining power of workers.

Effects of z on un

An increase in z leads to a higher required wage from workers, but firms can only afford to pay a lower wage, leading to higher unemployment un to reach equilibrium.

Expected Inflation and Phillips Curve Dynamics

At the core of the Phillips curve is the assumption about inflation expectations:
πe = E[πt + 1]
Where E[ ⋅ ] denotes the expectation operator. When expectations are well anchored, especially at low values of inflation, the Phillips curve maintains its downward slope.

Shift in Expectations

If inflation expectations are disanchored (such as during the 1970s), the relationship can break down, as seen from historical data where inflation accelerated despite high unemployment due to expected inflation catching up with realized inflation.

Dynamic Model of Expectations

In a dynamic world, expected inflation can be modeled as:
πe = θπt − 1 + (1 − θ)π̄
where π̄ is the target inflation rate (often around 2

The implication is that if θ approaches 1, expected inflation becomes much more responsive to previous inflation shocks, leading to persistent inflation against earlier Phillips curves.

Conclusion

Understanding the Phillips curve provides essential insight into monetary policy and inflation targeting. The dynamics of inflation expectations, the natural rate of unemployment, and economic shocks interact to determine inflation outcomes.

As we continue exploring macroeconomic models, this foundation will aid in addressing contemporary economic challenges such as rising inflation pressures.

Lecture Notes on IS-LM-PC Model and Current Economic Events

Introduction

The IS-LM-PC model combines various economic concepts discussed in previous lectures. It serves as a central model to analyze the interactions between the goods market (IS), money market (LM), and inflation dynamics (Phillips Curve, PC).

Current Economic Events

Banking Dynamics

A bank run occurs when depositors lose confidence, leading to mass withdrawals. The key factors in SVB’s situation:

Understanding the IS-LM-PC Model

The IS-LM-PC model consists of three core components: the IS curve, the LM curve, and the Phillips Curve.

IS Curve


Y = C(Y − T) + I(r) + G
where:

The IS curve represents equilibrium in the goods market.

LM Curve


M/P = L(r, Y)
where:

The LM curve represents equilibrium in the money market, linking the real interest rate and output.

Phillips Curve


π − πe =  − β(Y − Yn)
where:

The Phillips curve depicts the trade-off between inflation and unemployment/output.

Short-Run Dynamics

The short run analysis focuses on the immediate reactions to shocks in the economy, where the IS-LM model governs the output and inflation behavior.

Expected Inflation Dynamics

In the initial phases, the model assumes expected inflation is influenced by previous inflation rates.

Medium-Run Adjustments

Over time, the economy adjusts toward the natural rate of output and interest.

Natural Rate of Interest

The natural rate, r*, is defined such that monetary policy does not create inflationary or deflationary pressures:
Yn = C(Yn − T) + I(r*) + G.

Transitioning from Short Run to Medium Run

As inflationary pressures build, central banks must react:

Implications of the Model

Conclusion

The IS-LM-PC model offers a comprehensive framework for understanding the interplay between monetary policy, output fluctuations, and inflation dynamics. The recent events in the banking sector highlight the fragility of financial institutions and the critical importance of sound regulatory practices.

Lecture Notes: IS-LM-PC Model

Introduction

The IS-LM-PC model integrates the IS-LM analysis with the Phillips Curve (PC). It provides insights into the relationship between output, interest rates, inflation, and unemployment, particularly in the context of monetary policy and economic shocks.

Key Concepts

IS-LM Model

The IS-LM model represents the goods market (IS curve) and the money market (LM curve):

Phillips Curve

The Phillips Curve shows the inverse relationship between inflation and unemployment:
π = πe − β(u − un)
where:

Output Gap

The output gap is defined as the difference between actual output (Y) and potential output (Yn):
Output Gap = Y − Yn

Natural Rate of Unemployment

Potential output is achieved when unemployment is at its natural rate, defined as:
Yn = L ⋅ (1 − un)
where:

IS-LM-PC Model Integration

The IS-LM-PC model combines the output and inflation aspects by replacing unemployment with the output gap in the Phillips Curve, yielding:
π − πe = α(Y − Yn)
where α is a sensitivity parameter.

Dynamics of the Model

Short-Run Dynamics

In the short run, changes in the interest rate by the central bank affect the equilibrium level of output. If output exceeds potential output, inflation will rise:

Central Bank Response

When inflation rises, a responsible central bank typically raises interest rates, which can lead to a decrease in output over time. The implicit natural interest rate (Rn) is the rate that stabilizes the output at its potential level:
Rn = implied rate for equilibrium output

Anchored vs. Unanchored Expectations

Expectations about future inflation greatly impact the economy’s response to shocks:

Types of Shocks

Aggregate Demand Shocks

Aggregate demand shocks, such as fiscal consolidations, move the IS curve:

Supply Side Shocks

Supply side shocks, such as oil price increases, influence the Phillips Curve directly, shifting it outwards:

Current Economic Context

Financial Stability Concerns

Recent shocks, such as the situation at Silicon Valley Bank, illustrate how credit shocks can shift the IS curve leftward. The bank’s event resulted in reduced investment and increased inflationary pressures.

Market Reactions

The markets have responded to these shocks with anticipated changes in inflation:

Conclusion

Understanding the IS-LM-PC model enables analysts to navigate the complexities of macroeconomic dynamics, especially during periods of economic turbulence. The interplay between interest rates, output, and inflation, as illustrated in this model, is critical for effective monetary policy formulation.

Macroeconomic Growth and Long-Run Analysis

Introduction

This lecture focuses on macroeconomic growth, which examines phenomena occurring over decades rather than short-term business cycles. The discussion includes the significance of monetary policy, particularly in regard to interest rates and financial crises.

Key Concepts

Historical Context and Examples

Monetary policy’s impact is highlighted through historical episodes of interest rate hikes and their consequences. Key events include:

Growth Projections and Economic Forecasts

The International Monetary Fund (IMF) provides growth forecasts reflecting cyclical and structural factors. These forecasts show emerging markets typically grow faster than advanced economies.

Global Growth Estimates

In 2022, global growth was approximately 3.4% with advanced economies growing at 2.7% and emerging markets at 3.9%. Forecast for 2024 suggests a slowdown in growth due to economic conditions.

Understanding Economic Growth

Growth is crucial for evaluating the health of an economy. Gross Domestic Product (GDP) is often measured in constant prices (e.g., 2012 dollars) to accurately reflect economic changes over time.

The following observations reflect long-term economic growth:

Population Growth

The increase in the population from 63 million to 320 million in the U.S. correlates with economic growth, raising crucial questions regarding ongoing population changes in the global context.

Comparative GDP Analysis using Purchasing Power Parity (PPP)

When comparing GDP per capita across countries, adjustments are necessary to account for price level differences using Purchasing Power Parity (PPP). The main principles of PPP can be illustrated with the following hypothetical scenario:

Example

Assume two economies:

  1. U.S.: Household consumption includes one car ($10,000) and food ($10,000), totaling $20,000.

  2. Russia: Household consumption is 0.07 cars per year (costing 40, 000 rubles) and food (costing 80, 000 rubles), totaling 120, 000 rubles.

Given an exchange rate of 60 rubles/USD:
$$\text{US Consumption: } 20,000 \text{ USD}, \quad \text{Russian Consumption: } \frac{120,000 \text{ rubles}}{60 \text{ rubles/USD}} = 2,000 \text{ USD}$$
This suggests that without adjustments, it appears Russia is 10 times poorer than the U.S. However, real consumption must account for lower price levels in Russia.

PPP Adjusted Consumption

Using U.S. market prices:
Russian Household Consumption: (0.07 cars × 10, 000) + (1 food bundle × 10, 000) = 10, 700 USD
This indicates that the Russian household is actually 53% of the U.S. household’s purchasing power rather than 10 times poorer.

Growth Rates in Developed Economies

An analysis of growth rates from 1950 to 2017 reveals trends such as:

This suggests that poorer countries tend to grow faster than richer ones, aiding in the understanding of global economic convergence.

Production Function and Economic Growth

Long-run growth can be represented through a production function, typically expressed as:
Y = F(K, N)
Where Y is output, K is capital, and N is labor.

Key Properties of the Production Function

  1. Constant Returns to Scale: Doubling inputs leads to a doubling of output.

  2. Decreasing Returns to Capital: Increasing K while holding N constant leads to progressively smaller increases in Y.

Implications for Growth

Understanding the factors behind changes in per capita output is crucial. The two mechanisms driving changes are:

Notes on the Solow Growth Model

Introduction

The Solow Growth Model, developed by Robert Solow, focuses on long-term economic growth driven by capital accumulation, labor or population growth, and advances in technology. This model outlines key mechanisms for understanding how economies grow over time.

Key Concepts

Production Function

The production function exhibits constant returns to scale, leading to:
$$\frac{Y}{N} = f\left(\frac{K}{N}\right)$$
This function is increasing and concave due to the property of diminishing marginal returns to capital.

Investment and Savings

Assuming savings is proportional to income:
S = sY,  where s = saving rate ∈ [0, 1]
Investment in a closed economy is equal to savings.

Dynamics of Capital Accumulation

The evolution of capital per worker over time is described by the equation:
Kt + 1 = Kt + It − δKt
where:

Dividing by N for per worker terms gives:
$$\frac{K_{t+1}}{N} = \frac{K_t}{N} + \frac{I_t}{N} - \delta \frac{K_t}{N}$$

Steady State Analysis

In the steady state, output per worker and capital per worker remain constant. This results in:
$$0 = s f\left(\frac{K}{N}\right) - (\delta + g_N)\frac{K}{N}$$
Where gN is the population growth rate.

The steady-state capital per worker is given by:
$$\frac{K^*}{N} = \frac{s}{\delta + g_N}$$

Effects of Savings Rate Changes

When the savings rate increases:

This leads to a transitional growth phase with increased output per worker until a new steady state is achieved.

Population Growth Implications

If the population grows at a rate gN > 0, the steady state changes:
$$K^* = \frac{s}{\delta + g_N}$$
This indicates that output per worker may stabilize or decline depending on the growth of the population relative to output.

Conclusion

The Solow Growth Model provides a framework for analyzing how capital accumulation and population growth affect output in an economy. It emphasizes the role of savings for investment and the implications of diminishing returns in the growth process.

Technological Progress and Economic Growth

Introduction

Today, we will discuss the relationship between technological progress and economic growth. This topic is essential for understanding how economies develop and how human well-being is enhanced through innovation.

Recap from Previous Lecture

In the previous lecture, we focused on the role of capital accumulation in economic growth. We began with a production function that demonstrates constant returns to scale in capital and labor.

Key Concepts

Equations

The key equation derived was the capital accumulation equation:
kt + 1 = kt − δkt + it
where kt + 1 is the capital stock tomorrow, δ is the depreciation rate, and it is investment.

Adjustment for Population Growth

If we allow for population growth, we adjust the equation:
$$\frac{k_{t+1}}{n_{t+1}} = (1 - \delta - g_n) \frac{k_t}{n_t} + \text{Investment function}$$
where gn is the population growth rate.

Understanding the Impact of Population Growth

When population (n) grows, the capital per person (k/n) can decrease, even when the total capital remains constant. The introduction of gn (population growth rate) highlights this relationship. For instance, a greater gn means that more investment is needed just to maintain the capital per person.

Key Insight

If population growth is high, the investment must keep pace to maintain the capital-labor ratio.

Introduction to Technological Progress

The next step is to integrate technological progress (denoted as ga) into our growth model.

Total Factor Productivity (TFP)

Technological progress allows for producing more output from the same amount of capital and labor, leading to higher efficiency.

Modeling Technological Progress

We can model technological progress as an increase in effective labor, represented as an. The effectiveness of labor increases, similar to having more workers.

The Production Function with Technological Change

The production function now becomes:
Y = F(K, aN)
where K is the capital and N is the labor force.

Output per Effective Worker

Dividing by effective labor:
$$y = f\left(\frac{K}{aN}\right)$$
where y is output per effective worker.

Dynamic Behavior Under Technological Progress

The new equation regarding capital accumulation under technological progress becomes:
$$\frac{k_{t+1}}{a_t n_{t+1}} = \left(1 - \delta - g_a - g_n\right) \frac{k_t}{a_t n_t}$$
This equation demonstrates that the effective capital per worker changes over time based on both population growth and technological change.

Implications of Technological Progress

As ga increases, the economy can potentially experience higher growth rates over time:

Because technological progress allows for higher productivity, it becomes the principal driver for sustainable increases in output per person, beyond what capital accumulation can achieve alone.

Conclusion and Future Directions

We have explored how population growth and technological progress interrelate and their effects on economic growth. The next steps will further detail how to model these interactions more robustly.

The understanding of these dynamics is critical, especially as economies face challenges such as declining population growth rates in various regions across the world.

Growth Theory: Comprehensive Notes

Introduction

In this lecture, we will summarize the key elements of growth theory, focusing on what our models can and cannot explain regarding the great dispersion we observe in income per capita across the world.

Balanced Growth Theory

A balanced growth model assumes that all relevant variables grow at the same rate. This can be illustrated through the following:
1. Normalized Variables:
Yt = At ⋅ Ht ⋅ Kt1 − α ⋅ (At ⋅ Nt)α
Where:

2. Growth Rates: - The growth rate of output per effective worker is given by:
gY = (1 − α)gK + α(gA + gH)
In balanced growth, gA and gH remain constant.
3. Steady State Growth: In steady state, the growth rates for key variables are:
gK = gA + gN

gY = gA + gN

4. Implications:

Measuring Technological Progress

To measure the rate of technological change (gA), we can utilize the following formula based on the contributions of labor and capital:
1. Contribution from Labor:
gY|N = α ⋅ gN
Where:
gY|N = Growth of output due to growth in employment
2. Contribution from Capital:
gY|K = (1 − α) ⋅ gK
The total growth of output can be decomposed as follows:
gY = gY|N + gY|K + gA
The residual (gA) represents technological progress.

Growth Accounting Example: China (1978-2017)

These contributors can be expressed in terms of the relative output and saving rates.

Transitional Growth

Transitional growth occurs when a country is below its steady-state level, leading to faster growth due to capital accumulation.
1. If a country has below-steady-state levels of capital:
gOutput > gA + gN
Example: Post-war economies often experience transitional growth.
2. For China during growth episodes:
gK > gY > (gA + gN)

Condition for Balanced Growth

In the context of an extended model to include human capital (H): 1. Human capital model:
Y = A ⋅ Hh ⋅ K1 − α
2. Steady states will still yield gA and gH as before. If education is increased, the model predicts higher output without changing the growth dynamics fundamentally.

Education and Income Disparities

Education plays a crucial role in explaining differences in income per capita across countries. A rise in average years of schooling contributes positively to human capital:
gH = 0.1 ⋅ ΔYearsofSchooling

Empirical findings suggest that countries with higher education often exhibit higher income per capita:
Yi = A ⋅ Hiα ⋅ Ki1 − α

Evaluating Income Disparities

Despite accounting for savings rates and education, significant income disparities remain. The Solow Residual continues to play a vital role, indicating that technology levels vary drastically worldwide.

1. The relative technology output levels across countries:
$$A_i = \frac{Y_i}{K_i^{1-\alpha}H_i^{\alpha}}$$

This allows for considerable insights into how much of the output per worker disparities can be attributed to technology differences.

Conclusion

While models like the Solow model provide substantial insight, they struggle to account for variations in growth rates and income levels as affected by diverse factors, particularly those relating to institutions and technology adoption rates.

Future discussions will encompass the dynamics of open economies and integrate these modern growth theories into broader economic models.

Economic Theory and Current U.S. Economic Situation

Overview of the U.S. Economy Post-COVID

As economies begin to reopen from the COVID-19 pandemic, there has been excess demand over supply. The expected potential output, as described in the IS-LM-PC model, was slow to recover due to:

This resulted in a positive output gap, defined as output exceeding potential output (represented mathematically as Y > Y*), thereby exerting inflationary pressures described by the Phillips Curve.


Phillips Curve:  π = πe − β(Y − Y*)
Where:

Federal Reserve’s Response

Initially, the Federal Reserve (Fed) underestimated the persistence of inflation due to strong demand fueled by fiscal and monetary policies. As inflation rose:
Output: Y > Y*  ⟹  i
Where i is the interest rate. As such, policymakers prefer gradual changes, especially when hiking rates to prevent systemic failures in the banking sector.

Banking Sector Concerns

The resilience of large banks was initially reassuring. However, rapid deposit outflows led to a significant banking failure, most notably exemplified by the collapse of Silicon Valley Bank.

Economic Impact

Small and medium-sized banks, which primarily serve local businesses, faced much sharper declines in deposits, ultimately affecting their ability to lend. This created a contraction in the economy with a disproportionate impact on small businesses.


Banks in Gray (Small/Medium)  ⇒  High Share of Loans to Small Businesses
This leads to:
Y = C + I + G + NX  (AggregateDemand)
Where C is consumption, I is investment, G is government spending, and NX is net exports.

Wage Pressure and Labor Market Dynamics

Despite low unemployment rates, underlying wage pressures remain. The labor force participation declined during the pandemic but is now recovering.

Labor Force Participation

The change in labor force participation influences wage pressure, as follows:


$$\text{Wage Pressure} \propto \frac{W}{L} \quad \text{(where \(W\) is wages and \(L\) is labor supply)}$$

Immigration and Labor Supply

Immigration affects labor input significantly, with disruptions during COVID. The recovery in immigration can alleviate wage pressures.

Open Economy Concepts

The next section details how these concepts apply in an open economy framework.

Key Variables in an Open Economy

The U.S. generally has a trade deficit, meaning it imports more than it exports.

Exchange Rate Dynamics

When discussing currency valuation, we define appreciation and depreciation:


Appreciation: Ecurrent > Epast

Depreciation: Ecurrent < Epast

A real exchange rate R can be defined as:
$$R = \frac{E \cdot P_d}{P_f}$$
Where:

This metric allows for comparisons of relative prices between goods across countries.

Implications of Economic Integration

As economies integrate through trade and finance, synchronizing business cycles becomes more prevalent. The U.S. demonstrates remarkably synchronized cycles, especially during significant global events like the 2008 financial crisis and the COVID-19 pandemic.

Increasing Open-Economy Interdependence

Through intra-country trade and capital mobility, countries become increasingly exposed to each other’s economic conditions. This is particularly relevant as global events can have amplified impacts across integrated economies.

Conclusion

The U.S. economy is currently at a critical juncture, balancing the need for continued rate hikes to combat inflation while navigating the implications of a potential credit crunch that could lead to a slowdown. Understanding these dynamics in both closed and open economy contexts is vital for policymakers and economists alike.

Economics Lecture Notes: IS-LM Model in an Open Economy

Introduction

The lecture focuses on the IS-LM model, revisiting it within the context of an open economy. The key concepts discussed will include openness in goods and capital markets, real exchange rates, and demand for domestic versus foreign goods.

Concept of Openness

Openness in an economy can be defined in two major aspects:

Real Exchange Rate

The real exchange rate (ϵ) is defined as:
$$\epsilon = \frac{P^*}{P} \cdot E$$
where:

A rise in ϵ indicates a real appreciation of the domestic currency, meaning domestic goods become more expensive than foreign goods. Conversely, a fall in ϵ indicates a depreciation.

Investment and Returns

When considering investments, comparing the expected returns on domestic assets with foreign assets is crucial:

Uncovered Interest Parity Condition

The equilibrium condition for investors is given by:
$$(1 + i) = (1 + i^*) \cdot \frac{E}{E^*}$$
Where it states that interest rates must be equal when adjusted for expected changes in exchange rates.

Demand for Domestic versus Foreign Goods

In an open economy, we distinguish between:

Behavioral Assumptions

- Exports increase as foreign output (Y*) increases and decrease with an increase in the real exchange rate (ϵ):
X = f(Y*, ϵ)
- Imports increase with domestic output (Y) and also with the real exchange rate (ϵ):
M = f(Y, ϵ)

Equilibrium Output

To find equilibrium output, we use:
Y = ZZ
Where the intersection of the ZZ (demand for domestic goods) and the 45-degree line gives us equilibrium output.

Multipliers in Open Economies

The open economy has a lower multiplier effect due to:

Hence the multiplier effect is tempered by the leakages to imports.

Effects of Currency Depreciation

If a country faces a trade deficit and seeks to improve it through currency depreciation:

Policy Implications

To balance the expansion caused by depreciation, a government may choose to reduce spending or implement fiscal contraction.

Summary

The main learnings from this lecture include: - Differentiation between domestic demand and demand for domestic goods. - Understanding how exchange rates influence exports and imports. - Recognizing the implications of an open economy on multipliers and trade balances.

Conclusion

This lecture prepares us for the upcoming integration with financial markets in the context of the Mundell-Fleming model, emphasizing the interconnectedness of goods markets and financial markets in an open economy.

Notes on the Mundell-Fleming Model

Introduction

The Mundell-Fleming model is a critical tool for understanding the interactions between exchange rates, interest rates, and output in an open economy. The model is particularly important for short-term economic analysis and is likely to be a key focus for quizzes and examinations.

Exchange Rates

Definition and Interpretation

In this course, we define an increase in the exchange rate as an appreciation of the domestic currency (the dollar). Conversely, a decrease signifies a depreciation.

Key Observations

Key Economic Concepts

Uncovered Interest Parity

The Uncovered Interest Parity (UIP) condition is fundamental to the Mundell-Fleming model, expressing the relationship between exchange rates and interest rates.
$$E_t = \frac{(1+i_d)}{(1+i_f)}E_{t+1}$$
Where:

The principle behind UIP is that the expected rate of return on domestic assets must equal that of foreign assets when adjusted for exchange rate expectations.

Net Exports Function

Net exports (NX) influence aggregate demand. The NX function is influenced by three factors:
NX = NX(Yd, Yf, RER)
Where:

The function suggests:

Effects of Income Changes

Mundell-Fleming Model Framework

The model integrates the IS-LM framework by incorporating the effects of exchange rates:

IS Curve

The IS curve represents equilibrium in the goods market:
Y = C(Y − T) + I(r) + G + NX
Where:

Aggregate Demand in Open Economy

Revised aggregate demand accounts for the open economy context:
Y = C(Y − T) + I(r) + G + NX(Yd, Yf, RER)

LM Curve

The LM curve remains consistent with the closed economy, driven by monetary policy:
M/P = L(r, Y)
Where:

Policy Effects

Monetary Policy

An increase in the domestic interest rate will lead to:

Fiscal Policy

Expansionary fiscal policy (increased government spending) without a change in interest rates leads to:

Shocks and Adjustments

Expected Exchange Rate Changes

An increase in the expected exchange rate will:

Global Output Shocks

A decline in foreign output will:

Foreign Interest Rate Changes

An increase in foreign interest rates will:

Conclusion

The Mundell-Fleming model serves as a foundational component in international economics, offering insights into how monetary and fiscal policies affect exchange rates, output, and net exports in an open economy.

Notes on Exchange Rate Regimes and the Mundell-Fleming Model

Introduction

This document summarizes the key concepts discussed in the lecture concerning exchange rate regimes and the Mundell-Fleming model. We explore how different economic factors interact in open economies and the implications of various exchange rate systems.

Mundell-Fleming Model

The Mundell-Fleming model extends the IS-LM model to include international trade and finance.

Key Components

Experiments with the Model

  1. If the expected exchange rate Et + 1 increases:

    • The current exchange rate Et must rise

    • The IS curve shifts left due to a contraction in aggregate demand.

  2. If foreign output decreases:

    • Net exports decrease

    • The IS curve shifts left, indicating a recession.

  3. If the international interest rate rises while domestic interest rate remains constant:

    • The current exchange rate Et must depreciate

    • IS curve shifts right due to an increase in net exports.

Exchange Rate Regimes

Exchange rate arrangements can be broadly classified into floating (flexible) and fixed (pegged) regimes.

Floating Exchange Rate Regime

In a floating exchange rate regime, currency values are determined by market forces. Advantages include:

Disadvantages include:

Fixed Exchange Rate Regime

A fixed exchange rate regime involves pegging a currency to another major currency.

Hybrid Systems

Countries often use hybrid exchange rate systems that incorporate elements of both fixed and floating regimes.

Monetary and Fiscal Policy Implications

In a recession, countries in different regimes respond differently:

Flexible Exchange Rate

Fixed Exchange Rate

Speculative Attacks

Countries with fixed exchange rates may face speculative attacks if markets do not believe in the sustainability of the peg. To defend against such attacks:

Conclusion

The choice between exchange rate regimes is multifaceted and involves a trade-off between stability and policy autonomy. Countries may choose fixed exchange rates to combat inflation or stabilize their economy, while flexible regimes provide greater policy freedom but expose countries to excess volatility.

Lecture Notes: Expectations in Economics

Introduction

Expectations play a crucial role in economics, influencing decisions made by firms, consumers, and governments. Most economic and financial calculations involve evaluating future outcomes. Understanding how to assess the value of assets based on anticipated future cash flows is fundamental.

News and Expectations

Recent bank collapses, such as Silicon Valley Bank and First Republic Bank, exemplify the power of expectations in finance. The rapid withdrawal of deposits indicates that people’s expectations can influence the stability of financial institutions.

Stock Market Dynamics

The S&P 500 serves as a primary equity index in the U.S. market, capturing movements of large companies. Major swings in the index can be attributed to changes in expectations about:

For instance, the index dropped by 35% at the onset of COVID-19 and rallied by 114% by late 2021, only to decline again due to inflation concerns and subsequent interest rate increases.

Expected Present Discounted Value

To determine if the price of an asset today is fair, we calculate its expected present discounted value (EPDV). This concept combines several critical elements:

Key Concepts

Calculation of Present Value

The present value of a cash flow Zt, received at time t, can be generally represented as:
$$PV = \sum_{t=0}^{n} \frac{Z_t}{(1+i_t)^t}$$
Where:

If cash flows are known and consist of constant payments Z over n periods with a constant interest rate i, then the present value can be simplified to:
$$PV = Z \cdot \frac{1 - (1+i)^{-n}}{i}$$

Discounting Future Payments

If you expect $1 one year from now, it can be discounted at the interest rate i:
$$PV(1 \text{ year}) = \frac{1}{1+i}$$
Extending this, for $1 received two years from now, we have:
$$PV(2 \text{ years}) = \frac{1}{(1+i)^2}$$

Pricing Bonds

Bonds have varying maturities and coupon structures. The price of a bond can be determined using the present discounted value framework.

Yield to Maturity

Yield to maturity (YTM) is defined as the constant annual interest rate that equates the present value of a bond’s future cash flows to its current price. It can be calculated using:
$$P = \sum_{t=1}^{n} \frac{C_t}{(1 + YTM)^t}$$
Where Ct represents cash flows (coupon and face value payments).

Inversion and Curve Steepness

The yield curve illustrates the relationship between the yield and maturity of bonds. It can become inverted, indicating expectations of falling interest rates or economic downturns.

Constant Interest Rate Approximation

If the interest rates are expected to remain constant, the yield to maturity can be approximated as an average of the expected future rates:
$$YTM_2 \approx \frac{i_1 + E(i_1)}{2}$$

Conclusion

Understanding expectations and their impact on financial assets is vital for evaluating investments and managing economic policies. Future classes will build upon these concepts and explore their applications in various financial contexts.

Notes on Asset Pricing

Introduction to Asset Pricing

Asset pricing is centered on the notion that the payoff from an asset occurs in the future. This involves three key elements:

Present Value Calculation

To value a future cash flow, we need to understand its present value (PV). The present value calculation hinges on the idea that money today can earn interest.

Valuing $1 in the Future

To value $1 received next year:
$$PV = \frac{1}{1 + r}$$
where r is the interest rate. If you have $1 today, investing it at rate r yields:
FV = 1(1 + r) = 1 + r
Consequently, the present value of a future cash flow is discounted by the interest rate.

Multiple Periods

For cash flows over n years, the present discounted value of cash flows Zt for t years would be:
$$PV = \sum_{t=0}^{n} \frac{Z_t}{(1 + r)^t}$$

Expected Present Value

If we introduce uncertainties in payoffs and interest rates, we adjust our calculations based on expectations, such that:
$$PV = \sum_{t=0}^{n} \frac{\mathbb{E}[Z_t]}{(1 + \mathbb{E}[r])^t}$$
where 𝔼[Zt] and 𝔼[r] denote the expected cash flows and interest rates, respectively.

Special Cases

Bond Pricing

Bonds promise fixed cash flows over time. For a simple bond paying $100 at maturity with a price denoted as Pt:
$$P_t = \frac{100}{1 + r}$$
For multi-period bonds, say a two-year bond:
$$P_t = \frac{100}{(1 + r_1)(1 + r_2)}$$
where r1 and r2 are the one-year interest rates at times t and t + 1, respectively.

Arbitrage Pricing

Two instruments with the same maturity should yield comparable returns. This leads to the principle of arbitrage:
Return from a one-year bond = Expected return from holding a two-year bond for a year

Bond Yields

The yield on a bond is the constant interest rate that equates the present value of expected cash flows to the price of the bond:
$$P_t = \frac{100}{(1 + y)^2}$$
The yield is often interpreted as an average of expected future interest rates.

Stock Prices

Stocks differ from bonds primarily:

  1. Stocks pay dividends rather than fixed interest payments.

  2. Stocks don’t have a fixed maturity, and their cash flows can extend indefinitely.

Equity Price Calculation

For a stock priced Q with expected dividend D and price P after one year, the expected return on equity can be modeled as:
$$Q = \frac{D}{(1 + r + x_s)} + \frac{P_{t+1}}{(1 + r + x_s)}$$
where xs is the risk premium for equity investments.

The price Q can be rearranged to capture the expected dividends and future price:
$$Q = \sum_{t=1}^{\infty} \frac{D_t}{(1 + r + x_s)^t}$$

Monetary Policy Impact

An expansionary monetary policy (a decrease in interest rates) influences the price of both bonds and stocks by reducing discount rates. Thus:

Consumer Spending Impact

An increase in consumer spending may have a dual effect:

Risk Premium Dynamics

The risk premium, particularly in equity markets, is sensitive to economic conditions, which can lead to significant fluctuations in asset prices, indicating high market volatility especially during economic crises.

Bubbles and Market Psychology

Asset prices can exhibit irrational exuberance leading to bubbles, characterized by unsustainable price increases. Historical examples show that when asset prices soar without fundamental backing, they often decline sharply, emphasizing the importance of market psychology in asset pricing.

Expectations in Economics: Notes on Consumption and Investment

Introduction

Expectations play a significant role in economics, especially in asset pricing and the broader economic models discussed throughout the course. This document provides a detailed exploration of how expectations affect consumption and investment using the IS-LM model as a framework.

The Role of Expectations in Economics

Understanding Expectations

Economics heavily relies on expectations about the future. All economic actors—investors, consumers, firms, and governments—base their decisions on anticipated future conditions rather than solely current conditions.

Key Concepts

Consumption Function

Traditional Consumption Function

Traditionally, consumption (C) was modeled as a function of current disposable income (Yd):
C = C0 + c ⋅ Yd
where C0 is autonomous consumption and c is the marginal propensity to consume.

Permanent vs. Temporary Income

Real expectations indicate that consumers smooth consumption over their lifetime, treating temporary income fluctuations differently:

Realistic Consumption Function

A more realistic consumption function includes both current income and total wealth:
C = C0 + c1 ⋅ Yd + c2 ⋅ W
where c1 and c2 reflect the impacts of current income and wealth on consumption decisions, respectively.

Investment Decision by Firms

Investment Function

Investment decisions depend on expected future cash flows from capital assets and current economic conditions:
I = f(V, Y, r, future variables)
where:

Expected Present Value of Cash Flows

The value of an investment depends on:

Financial Frictions

A firm’s ability to borrow is often constrained by its current profitability, leading to the necessity of retaining earnings.

IS-LM Model with Expectations

Modified Aggregate Demand

Incorporating expectations into IS-LM, aggregate demand is now a function of both current and expected future variables:
AD = f(Yt, Yf, G, Tt, Tf, rt, rf)
where Yf, Tf, and rf are expected future values of income, taxes, and interest rates, respectively.

Shifts in the IS Curve

The modified IS curve will shift more or less based on the permanence of changes in economic variables:

Monetary Policy and Expectations

Central Bank Influence

The effectiveness of monetary policy lies in managing expectations:

Counterintuitive Fiscal Policies

Fiscal contractions can lead to expansionary outcomes if they are perceived as reducing future risks or if they are associated with future monetary easing.

Examples of Expansionary Fiscal Contractions

Historical cases, such as the fiscal consolidation in Ireland in the late ’80s, illustrate how positive expectations can result in economic growth despite short-term austerity measures.

Conclusion

Expectations play a critical role in shaping economic behavior, influencing investment, consumption, and overall aggregate demand. Understanding the expectations framework enhances the predictive power of economic models like the IS-LM model while showcasing the importance of managing expectations in effective monetary and fiscal policy.