contents

Microeconomics

What is Microeconomics?

Supply and Demand Model

Introduction to Supply and Demand

Market Dynamics

Positive vs. Normative Analysis

Market Structures

Conclusion

Notes on Consumer Choice and Demand Curve Derivation

Introduction

The demand curve represents consumer preferences and choices in the context of the supply and demand model in economics. The objective is to understand how these curves emerge from the utility maximization behavior of consumers.

Model of Consumer Decision Making

The model of consumer decision making revolves around two essential components:

  1. Consumer Preferences: What individuals want.

  2. Budget Constraint: What individuals can afford.

The goal is to maximize utility (happiness) given these constraints.

Preferences and Utility Functions

Assumptions about Preferences

To build our model, we start with three key assumptions regarding preferences:

Indifference Curves

Indifference curves graphically represent preferences. Each curve represents a set of consumption combinations among which consumers are indifferent.

Utility Functions

Every individual has an underlying utility function, representing their preferences mathematically. A simple utility function for two goods (e.g., pizza and cookies) could be:
U(P,C)=P×C
where P is the amount of pizza and C is the amount of cookies.

Marginal Utility

Marginal utility is the change in utility resulting from a one-unit change in the quantity of a good.
MUC=UC
The concept of diminishing marginal utility suggests that as more of a good is consumed, the additional utility gained from consuming an extra unit decreases.

Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS)

The marginal rate of substitution tells us the rate at which a consumer is willing to substitute one good for another while keeping utility constant. It is defined as:
MRS=MUCMUP
where MUC is the marginal utility of cookies and MUP is the marginal utility of pizza.

Properties of MRS

Practical Implications of Utility Theory

Understanding these concepts helps explain real-world pricing strategies. For instance:

The prices for larger sizes of beverages (in stores like Starbucks or McDonald’s) often reflect the diminishing marginal utility; thus, larger sizes are disproportionately cheaper than smaller ones for consumers.

Conclusion

Today’s focus was on consumer preferences, utility functions, and the derivation of the demand curve from these concepts. The next topic will involve budget constraints and the implications for demand.

Consumer Choice and Budget Constraints

Introduction

In this lecture, we focus on consumer choice under budget constraints. Specifically, we will elaborate on the construction of budget constraints, how consumers make constrained choices, and an illustrative example using food stamps.

Budget Constraints

A budget constraint represents the limit on a consumer’s choices, given their income and the prices of goods.

Fundamental Axiom of Consumer Choice

The fundamental axiom of consumer choice is that "more is better." However, consumers are limited by their budget, which defines what goods they can purchase.

Assumptions

For the purpose of this discussion, we assume:

Let:

The budget constraint can be represented mathematically as:
pP ⋅ P + pC ⋅ C ≤ Y

Calculation of Intercepts

The intercepts of the budget constraint are calculated as follows:

For example, with Y = 72, pP = 12, and pC = 6:

Slope of the Budget Constraint

The slope of the budget constraint (the Marginal Rate of Transformation, MRT) is given by:
MRT=pCpP
This indicates the rate at which one good can be substituted for another while keeping the budget constant.

Opportunity Cost

The opportunity cost is the value of the next best alternative foregone. For example, the opportunity cost of one slice of pizza equals two cookies when the prices are as defined above.

Consumer Choices Under Constraints

Consumers aim to maximize their utility subject to their budget constraint.

Utility Maximization

Consumers will choose a combination of goods that maximizes their utility, subject to the budget constraint. The utility can be represented with a function:
U(P,C)=PC

Indifference Curves

Graphically, the highest attainable indifference curve under the budget constraint represents the optimal choice for the consumer. The point of tangency between the indifference curve and the budget constraint represents the optimal consumption bundle.

Food Stamps Example

Understanding SNAP

Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program (SNAP, formerly food stamps) affects consumer choices:

  1. SNAP provides funds specifically for purchasing food.

  2. Compare cash transfers versus food stamps.

Budget Constraints with SNAP

When consumers receive cash, the budget constraint shifts outward, allowing more flexibility in choice. For food stamps, the budget constraint may kink, reflecting restrictions on spending.

Mathematical Formulation


Cash Transfer Budget : Y + cash → new budget constraint

Graph of Cash Subsidy

Comparing Choices

Two different consumer types:

Conclusion

Understanding consumer behavior under budget constraints helps to illustrate broader economic theories concerning welfare programs like food stamps. While empirical evidence suggests mixing cash transfers may improve well-being, the paternalistic reasoning for SNAP designs calls into question the nature of consumer choice.

Notes on Consumer Choice and Demand Theory

Introduction

In this lecture, we will derive demand curves using consumer choice theory, discuss the elasticity of demand, the effect of income changes on demand, and analyze the impact of price changes using the substitution and income effects.

Deriving Demand Curves

We start with the foundational model in consumer choice. The demand for goods can be derived from a utility function.

Example Setup

Assume the utility function is of the form:
u = P ⋅ C
where C represents cookies, and the price of cookies Pc is given. Let:

Budget Constraints

Define the budget constraint:
BC : Pc ⋅ C + Pp ⋅ P = I
For the initial prices:

If prices change, new budget constraints can be derived as shown in the following figures (placeholders for figures will be identified below):

Graphical Analysis

When Pc rises to $9:

The slope of the new budget constraint:
slope=PcPp912=34

The effect of price changes shows a move from point A (6 cookies, 3 pizzas) to point B (4 cookies, 3 pizzas).

When Pc falls to $4:

Now, the new budget constraint slope:
slope=412=13

This moves from point A to point C (3 pizzas, 9 cookies).

Demand Curves

From these points, a demand curve can be plotted. The demand curve represents the relationship between price and quantity demanded:
Demand Curve: Qd = f(P)
For instance:

Elasticity of Demand

Definition

The elasticity of demand (ϵ) is defined as:
ϵ=ΔQ/Q0ΔP/P0
It measures the percentage change in quantity demanded in response to a percentage change in price.

Types of Elasticity

Income Effect and Substitution Effect

Effects of Price Change

When the price of a good changes:

Giffen Goods

A Giffen good is a rare case where higher prices lead to higher quantity demanded due to the dominance of inferior income effects.

Conclusion

Understanding the derivation and behavior of demand curves through changes in price and income helps clarify consumer behaviour in markets. The key takeaways include:

Producer Theory Notes

Introduction to Producer Theory

Producer theory expands on consumer theory, moving from the demand curve to the supply curve. While consumer theory primarily dealt with optimizing utility given income and prices, producer theory involves firms that decide their income based on production choices.

Key Concepts

Production Function

Producers utilize a production function to transform inputs (labor and capital) into output. The general form is:


q = f(L, K)
where:

We differentiate between firm output (q) and market output (Q).

Factors of Production

The inputs in production are categorized into:

Inputs can be classified as:

The distinction between short run and long run is critical:

Short Run Production

In the short run, firms aim to maximize profits by hiring labor while keeping capital fixed. The short-run production function can be expressed as:


q = f(L, )

The focus is primarily on Marginal Product of Labor (MPL), which is defined as:


MPL=ΔqΔL

Diminishing marginal product states that as more units of labor are added, the contribution of each additional unit of labor to output eventually decreases.

Long Run Production

In the long run, firms have the flexibility to change both labor and capital. The production function remains similar:


q = f(L, K)

Firms must decide the optimal mix of labor and capital. The concept of Isoquants is used here, representing combinations of labor and capital that yield the same level of output.

Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution (MRTS)

The MRTS of labor for capital is defined as the slope of the isoquant:


MRTS=MPLMPK
where:

Returns to Scale

Returns to scale assesses how output responds when all inputs are increased proportionally:

Productivity and Its Implications

Total Factor Productivity (TFP)

Productivity is defined as the efficiency of converting inputs into outputs, which can be influenced by innovations in production processes:


q = A ⋅ f(L, K)
where A signifies the total factor productivity at time t.

Historical Context

Notable economists like Thomas Malthus predicted limits on productivity due to fixed agricultural land, but innovations in technology have allowed more efficient production techniques which have led to increased productivity over time.

The trends in productivity growth in the U.S. over the decades illustrate these concepts:

Distribution of Gains

The distribution of productivity gains raises important questions regarding equity:

Conclusion

Understanding producer theory helps frame the economic realities of production, profitability, and productivity. It highlights not just the technical aspects of how firms operate but also the broader implications for societal wealth and equity.

Producer Theory: Cost Functions and Production Theory

Introduction

In the lecture, we delve into producer theory, focusing on how producers maximize profits by minimizing costs. By understanding how costs vary with output, we can derive cost functions that help shape supply curves.

Short-Run Cost Curves

Cost Components

In the short run, we consider:

Production Function

The production function we work with is:
q=LK
where:

Cost Function Derivation

The cost of production can be represented as:
C = r ⋅ K + w ⋅ L
where:

Assuming specific values:
Let r = 10 and w = 5.

To derive the cost function, replace L using the production function:

1. From q=LK, we can isolate L:
L=q2K

2. Substitute L into the cost function:
C=rK+w(q2K)=10K+5q2K

For a fixed level of capital K = 1:
C = 10 + 5q2
Thus, the short-run cost function is:
Cost Function: C = 10 + 5q2

Marginal Cost and Average Cost

Definitions

Intuition Behind Average and Marginal Costs

Long-Run Cost Curves

Long-Run vs Short-Run

In the long run:


C = wL + rK

Isocost Curves

Isocost lines represent combinations of L and K that yield the same cost. The slope of the isocost curve is given by:
slope=wr

Optimal Input Mix

The optimal input mix occurs at the tangency between an isoquant (representing production levels) and an isocost line:
MPLMPK=wr
where MPL and MPK are the marginal products of labor and capital, respectively.

Long Run Expansion Path

The long-run expansion path indicates how the optimal combination of inputs changes with the quantity produced.

Variable Relationships

The long-run average cost curve represents the lowest possible costs for producing each quantity level. It is derived from the various short-run cost curves corresponding to different production levels:

Deriving the Long-Run Cost Function

Given production and input prices, we could derive the long-run cost function from:
TC = C(L, K) where L and K have been optimized

Conclusion

Understanding the relationship between input costs and production can guide firms in making strategic choices about production capabilities. The derived functions emphasize that being able to adjust production factors in the long run yields lower costs compared to the restricted decisions available in the short run.

Notes on Cost Concepts and Perfect Competition

Cost Concepts

Fixed vs Sunk Costs

Sunk Cost Fallacy

Perfect Competition

Definition

Conditions for Perfect Competition

Demand for Firm vs Market Demand

Elasticity of Demand

Profit Maximization

Definition of Profit

Maximizing Profit: The Optimal Condition

Revenue and Cost Functions

Effects of Taxes on Costs and Production

Per Unit Tax

Decision to Shut Down

Calculating Profits

Conclusion

Perfect competition serves as an ideal benchmark for understanding economic principles, and concepts such as sunk costs and profit maximization are critical in evaluating firm behavior in real markets.

Lecture Notes on Profit Maximization and Market Supply

Introduction

These notes cover concepts of profit maximization under perfect competition, shutdown decisions, and long-run competitive equilibrium including various supply curves and cost functions.

Cost Functions and Profit Maximization

Cost Function

The cost function discussed is:
C(q) = 10 + 5q2
Where C represents total cost and q represents the quantity of goods produced.

Calculating Profits


Profits = Revenues − Costs
Given that revenues are represented as R = P × q and costs as C(q), we can express profits per unit as:
Profits per unit = P − Average Cost

Average Cost Calculation

Average cost at a production level q = 3:
Average Cost=C(q)q=10+5q2q=103+5q
For q = 3, this yields:
Average Cost=103+15=18.33

Finding Optimal Quantity

The optimal production level q* is achieved where:
P = MC
For a price P = 30, equating this to marginal cost gives:
MC=dCdq=10q
By solving 10q = 30, we find:
q* = 3
Using the values, profits per unit becomes:
Profits per unit = 30 − 18.33 = 11.67
Total profits when producing 3 units:
Total Profits = 3 × 11.67 = 35

Impact of Taxes on Profits

New Cost Function with Tax

Introducing a tax of $10 per unit modifies the cost function to:
C(q) = 10 + 5q2 + 10q
Thus:
MC = 10 + 10q
Setting MC = P for price of 30, we solve:
10 + 10q = 30 ⟹ q* = 2
Calculating new average cost at q = 2:
Average Cost=C(2)2=10+20+202=25
New profits per unit are:
Profits per unit = 30 − 25 = 5
Thus, total profits:
Total Profits = 2 × 5 = 10

Shutdown Decision

Definition of Shutdown

In the short run, a firm may opt to produce zero units; this represents a short-run shutdown decision.

Shutdown Condition

Consider if the price drops to $10 with no tax:
Profits = 10 − (10 + 5) =  − 5
If the firm shuts down:
Profits = 0 − 10 =  − 10
Thus, as long as total revenue exceeds variable costs, it’s preferable to continue production.

Key Shutdown Rule

A firm should only shut down when:
P < Average Variable Cost

Average Variable Cost=Variable Costsq

Long-run Competition Equilibrium

Entering and Exiting the Market

In the long run, firms enter or exit the market until:
Profits = 0  (Long-run equilibrium)

Effect of Entry on Supply Curves

As firms enter the market, the supply increases:

Deriving Market Supply Curve

Market Supply Curve from Individual Firm Supply Curves

The market supply curve is derived by:
Market Supply = ∑Individual Supply
With an increase in firms, the market supply becomes more elastic.

Conclusion

Understanding that profit maximization leads firms towards zero long-term profits under perfect competition emphasizes the importance of cost minimization. Real-world deviations such as barriers to entry, firm heterogeneity, and variable input prices provide complexities that affect these theoretical predictions.

Supply and Demand Economics: Detailed Notes

Introduction

In economics, the supply and demand framework is fundamental for understanding how markets function. In this lecture, we revisit the concepts explored from our first discussion on supply and demand curves, investigating their origins, shifts, and implications.

Review of Supply and Demand

Graphical Representation

The supply and demand curves can be represented on a graph:

Equilibrium

The point where the supply and demand curves intersect represents market equilibrium (E). At this point, the quantity supplied equals the quantity demanded, which can be mathematically expressed as:
Qd(P) = Qs(P)
where Qd is the quantity demanded and Qs is the quantity supplied at price P.

Shifts in Supply and Demand Curves

Demand Curve Shifts

Shifts in the demand curve occur due to several factors:

  1. Changes in Tastes or Preferences: If preferences change in favor of a good, the demand increases, shifting the curve to the right D1 → D2.

  2. Income Changes: An increase in consumer income generally shifts the demand for normal goods to the right.

  3. Changes in Prices of Related Goods: If the price of a complementary good rises, the demand for the associated good may decrease.

  4. Market Size: An increase in market size (more consumers) shifts the demand curve to the right.

  5. Expectations of Future Prices: If consumers anticipate a price increase, they may buy more now.

Supply Curve Shifts

Supply curves can shift due to:

  1. Changes in Input Costs: Increases in the costs of production shift the supply curve to the left.

  2. Technological Advancements: Improvements in technology usually lead to more efficient production, causing the supply curve to shift to the right.

Example Scenarios

Consumer Surplus

Consumer surplus is defined as the benefit that consumers receive when they pay a price lower than what they are willing to pay. It can be represented graphically as:
Consumer Surplus = ∫0Q*(D(Q) − P) dQ
where P is the market price and Q* is the equilibrium quantity.

Graphical Representation

The consumer surplus is visually represented by the area above the price level and below the demand curve. If demand is perfectly inelastic, consumer surplus can become infinite as consumers are willing to pay anything for the good.

Producer Surplus

Producer surplus is the difference between what producers are willing to accept for a good and what they actually receive, mathematically represented as:
Producer Surplus = P − C(Q)
where C(Q) represents the marginal cost of production. The producer surplus is visually represented by the area below the price level and above the supply curve.

Market Producer Surplus

The total producer surplus in the market can be found by aggregating the surpluses across all firms:
Total Producer Surplus = ∫0Q*(P − S(Q)) dQ

Welfare Economics

Welfare economics utilizes the concepts of consumer and producer surplus to evaluate the overall well-being of society in the framework of market efficiency and allocate resources.

Key Concepts

Conclusion

Understanding supply and demand curves, their shifts, and the resulting surpluses is essential for analyzing market behaviors. These concepts also serve as the foundation for more advanced economic theories and policies.

Notes on Welfare Economics

Introduction to Welfare Economics

Welfare economics is divided into two main branches:

Concepts of Welfare

First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics

The first fundamental theorem states:

Under certain assumptions, a competitive equilibrium leads to a Pareto efficient allocation of resources.

Mathematically, social welfare W can be defined as:
W = CS + PS
Where:

The allocation where supply equals demand maximizes social welfare under market conditions.

Deadweight Loss Definition

Deadweight loss occurs due to inefficiencies in the market, representing the net reduction in welfare from trades that do not occur.

Applications of Welfare Economics

Case Study: Gas Market

In a scenario where supply shocks (e.g., an oil crisis) drive prices up:

Efficacy of Market Solutions

In instances of market failure due to regulations:

Conclusions

Welfare economics strives to identify effective and fair resource allocation strategies. The balance between efficiency and equity represents a critical ongoing challenge in economic policy formulation.

Economics Notes: Monopoly and Market Power

Introduction

Understanding Monopoly

Definition of Monopoly

Key Characteristics of Monopoly

Profit Maximization for Monopolists

Profit Definition


π = R − C
where π is profit, R is total revenue, and C is total cost.

Condition for Profit Maximization

Marginal Revenue for Monopolists

Deriving Marginal Revenue

Example of Demand Curve

Monopoly Profit Maximization Example

Cost Function

Assume the cost function is:
C = 12 + Q2
Thus, marginal cost is:
MC=dCdQ=2Q

Setting MR Equal to MC

To maximize profits:
24 − 2Q = 2Q
From which we solve:
24 = 4Q  ⇒  Q* = 6

Finding the Optimal Price

For Q* = 6:
P* = 24 − 6 = 18

Market Power and Price Discrimination

Definition of Market Power

Price Discrimination

Examples of Price Discrimination

Welfare Effects of Monopoly

Consumer and Producer Surplus

Deadweight Loss in Monopoly

When monopolists produce less than the socially optimal quantity, there are units that could have been produced that are foregone, resulting in deadweight loss (C + E) in the market.

Conclusion on Market Failure

Notes on Monopolies

Introduction

Monopolies are one extreme on the market structure spectrum, contrasting with perfectly competitive firms which face a perfectly elastic demand curve and can sell at market price. Monopolists, on the other hand, can set prices but undersupply, resulting in deadweight loss.

Sources of Monopoly

Monopolies arise from two primary sources:

Cost Advantages

Some monopolies stem from inherent cost advantages in the market. These can occur when:

Natural Monopoly

A natural monopoly exists when:

One firm can produce at a lower average cost than multiple firms for all relevant output levels.

This occurs typically in industries with high fixed costs and low marginal costs (e.g., water utilities). The average cost in such scenarios typically declines due to high initial fixed costs that are spread over a larger quantity of output.


AC=FC+VC(Q)Q
Where FC is fixed cost, VC is variable cost, and Q is quantity produced.

Government Action

Governments can also create monopolies through various means. This includes:

Deadweight loss arising from monopolies can be illustrated by the following equation:
DWL=12(PmMC)(QcQm)
Where Pm is the monopolist’s price, MC is marginal cost, Qc is the competitive quantity, and Qm is the monopolist’s quantity.

Regulating Monopolies

Regulation can have different effects on monopolistic markets. One approach is to set price ceilings to mimic competitive outcomes:

However, practical challenges arise:

Contestable Markets

A concept termed "contestable markets" refers to scenarios where a monopoly can exist but without significant market power due to the low barriers to entry. If firms can easily enter and exit the market, this may limit the monopolist’s pricing power despite a single firm operating in the market.

Case Study: Airline Deregulation

Historically, following the deregulation of the airline industry:

Illustrating the outcomes, we find that:

  1. Cheaper flights.

  2. Increased competition led to lower average costs.

  3. Creation of the hub-and-spoke model by airlines, resulting in some monopolistic behaviors at airports.

Conclusion

Monopolies can arise legitimately through cost advantages or government action, as seen with natural monopolies and patents. While regulation can address monopolistic inefficiencies, it faces practical challenges. Contestable markets present an interesting dimension where monopoly does not necessarily mean market power. The discussion on airline deregulation exemplifies these concepts and their real-world implications.

Notes on Oligopoly and Game Theory

Introduction

The lecture discusses the market structure of oligopoly, which is characterized by a small number of firms competing with each other, unlike perfect competition or monopoly. Oligopoly markets are marked by barriers to entry that prevent unlimited firms from entering the market.

Key Concepts

Oligopoly

An oligopoly is defined as a market structure wherein:

An example of an oligopoly is the automobile industry, controlled by a handful of major manufacturers.

Cooperative vs Non-Cooperative Behavior

Within oligopoly markets, firms can behave either cooperatively (forming a cartel) or non-cooperatively:

Game Theory

Game theory is the mathematical study of interaction among rational decision-makers. In non-cooperative oligopolies, the Nash equilibrium is a primary concept:
Nash Equilibrium:   No player has an incentive to change their strategy given the strategies of others.

Prisoner’s Dilemma

A classic example to illustrate non-cooperativity in game theory is the Prisoner’s Dilemma. The payoff matrix for two prisoners is structured as follows:

(1, 1) (5, 0)
(0, 5) (2, 2)

Where the outcome represents years in prison:

In this case, the Nash equilibrium occurs when both players choose to talk, leading to a suboptimal outcome.

Application to Economics

Focusing on advertising strategies between two companies, for instance, Coca-Cola and Pepsi, involves similar logic. Assuming:

The equilibrium is then created where:
If qC is Coca-Cola’s output and qP is Pepsi’s, then:

RevenueC = P ⋅ qC = (339 − qC − qP)qC

Cournot Model

The Cournot model describes a non-cooperative oligopoly where firms compete in quantities. The setup involves:

Given a demand function P = 339 − Q (where Q = qA + qU), where qA and qU represent the output of American and United Airlines, respectively, the profit-maximizing conditions can be derived:
RevenueA=PqA=(339(qA+qU))qAMarginal RevenueA=3392qAqUSet MR equal to MC (147):3392qAqU=147

This leads to the best response functions:
qA=9612qUqU=9612qA

Solving the above simultaneous equations will yield the Cournot equilibrium quantities for both firms.

Conclusion

The lecture emphasizes the importance of game theory in understanding oligopoly behavior. The Cournot model serves as a crucial analytical framework by illustrating how firms strategically interact in an oligopoly setting.

Notes on Oligopoly and Cartels

Introduction to Oligopoly

In the study of oligopoly, we distinguish between cooperative and non-cooperative equilibria. A key concept in achieving better outcomes in oligopolistic markets is cooperation among firms, often manifesting as cartels.

Cartels and Cooperative Outcomes

Consider the example of two firms (American Airlines and United Airlines). We previously analyzed the demand curve for this market:
P = 339 − Q
where P is price and Q is the quantity of flights.

The marginal cost MC for both firms is given as:
MC = 147

In a monopoly situation (considered as a cooperative equilibrium), the monopolist’s marginal revenue MR can be calculated as:
MR = 339 − 2Q
Setting MR = MC:
339 − 2Q = 147
Solving for Q:
Q = 96
The optimal price then, from the demand curve:
P = 339 − 96 = 243

When these firms cooperate by becoming a cartel, each firm operates at:
QA = QB = 48
Total profits for each firm can be expressed as:
Profit = QA × (P − MC) = 48 × (243 − 147) = 4, 608

Non-Cooperative Equilibrium

In a non-cooperative outcome where each firm operates independently, the total quantity offered can be represented as:
Q = 64
The price would thus be:
P = 339 − 128 = 211
Calculating profits under non-cooperation:
Profit = 64 × (211 − 147) = 4, 096

We see that cooperation improves profits by 512,orapproximately12.5.

Why Don’t Cartels Form?

Game Theory and Cartel Instability

When a firm, say American Airlines, decides to cheat by increasing its flights to QA = 50, the market price adjusts:
P = 339 − 98 = 241
New profits for American Airlines:
Profit = 50 × (241 − 147) = 4, 700
And for United Airlines:
Profit = 48 × (241 − 147) = 4, 512
This scenario leads to decreased total market profits and eventually leads to the breakdown of the cartel.

Antitrust Laws

Antitrust legislation exists to prevent firms from engaging in cartel behavior. Historical examples include:

Government-Made Cartels

Countries can also create cartels, as seen with Japan’s voluntary export restraint in the 1980s, leading to elevated prices for vehicles in the U.S.

Comparing Market Structures

Cournot vs. Bertrand Competition

Cournot Competition

In Cournot competition, firms fix quantities:
P = MC  (for competitive equilibrium)
As the number of firms, n, increases, the markup reduces. The relationship can be expressed as:
Markup1n(elasticity of demand)

Bertrand Competition

In Bertrand competition, firms are price competitors. Notably:

Product Differentiation

Firms and producers strive to differentiate their products in Bertrand competition settings. This differentiation enables them to maintain higher prices and potential for increased profits despite competition.

Examples

Conclusion

Understanding the dynamics of oligopolies, cartels, and different competition models allows economists and policymakers to make informed decisions that balance the needs of consumers against the interests of businesses.

Lecture Notes on Factor Markets

Introduction to Factor Markets

In this lecture series, we will explore where input prices, particularly wages (w) and rental rates of capital (r), come from. Factor markets are essential for determining these prices crucial to our economy.

Outline of the Lecture Series

  1. Factor Demand: General demand for labor and capital.

  2. Factor Supply: Understanding where supply originates.

  3. Equilibrium: Determining how wages and interest rates are established.

Factor Demand

Assuming perfectly competitive factor markets:

Short Run Labor Demand

In the short run, capital is fixed, and the firm decides whether to hire an additional worker.

Marginal Benefit and Marginal Cost
Optimization Condition

To optimize labor demand:
MRPL = w
where MRPL = MPL × P. Therefore:
MPL × P = w

Labor Supply Elasticity

The labor supply curve is horizontal in a perfectly competitive labor market.

Demand Curve

The labor demand curve slopes downwards due to diminishing returns:

Long Run Labor Demand

In the long run, both labor and capital can adjust. Long-run labor demand is more elastic as firms can optimize both inputs.

Comparison with Short Run

Two short-run demand curves at different levels of capital highlight the flexibility in long-run optimization.

Capital Demand

Like labor, capital demand is determined by:
MRPK = r
where MRPK = MPK × P.

This indicates:

Labor Supply

Labor supply at the firm level is perfectly elastic, but market labor supply is not.

Modeling Labor Supply


H = 24 − l
where l is leisure hours.

Budget Constraint Characteristics

Indifference curves display preferences between earned wages (consumption) and leisure.

Opportunity Cost

The price of leisure is equal to the wage (w):

Labor Supply Elasticity and Substitution Effects

Income and Substitution Effects

When wages change:

Graphs of the Trade-offs

  1. Illustrating the initial budget constraint.

  2. New budget constraint after a wage increase.

Elasticities of Labor Supply

In historical studies, men showed inelastic labor supply while women showed higher elasticity due to increased participation in the workforce.

Child Labor Implications

Discussion about the impact of international trade on child labor dynamics reveals that:

Conclusion

Understanding factor markets is essential for comprehending wages, employment levels, and economic behavior overall. The relationship between wages, labor supply, and social elements is nuanced and requires careful analysis.

Notes on Labor and Capital Markets

Introduction to Factor Markets

Today, we discuss factor markets with a focus on the labor market and the implications of a minimum wage.

Labor Market Equilibrium

In the labor market, we examine the supply and demand for labor, considering workers’ decisions between work and leisure.

Equilibrium

Minimum Wage

Welfare Implications

Consumer surplus for firms and producer surplus for workers is affected:

Thus, applying a minimum wage may increase worker welfare but decrease overall social welfare.

Empirical Evidence on Minimum Wage

Various studies have shown that employment levels in states raising the minimum wage do not significantly decrease:

Explanations

Three potential explanations for finding no decrease in employment:

  1. Minimum wage not binding.

  2. Labor supply is perfectly inelastic.

  3. Non-competitive labor markets (monopsony).

Monopsony in Labor Markets

In a monopsony:


W < MRPL

With a binding minimum wage above what workers earn in a monopsony market, firms may not fire workers due to:
MRPL > Wmin
The result is a mere transfer of surplus from the firm to the worker without deadweight loss.

Capital Markets

Definition of Capital

Capital represents the diversion of current consumption towards future consumption. Its forms include buildings, machines, and financial instruments.

Equilibrium in Capital Markets

Interest Rate

The equilibrium interest rate reflects the interaction between the demand for capital and the supply provided by savers.

Intertemporal Choice

Intertemporal choice concerns how much to consume today versus tomorrow, typically modeled as: - Present Consumption (C1) vs. Future Consumption (C2)
C2=C1(1+r)1
Where r is the interest rate.

Effects of Interest Rate Changes

If the interest rate rises:

  1. The opportunity cost of consuming today increases (substitution effect).

  2. Higher interest income may lead to increased wealth (income effect).

The net effect on consumption today and saving can be ambiguous.

Conclusion

These discussions on labor and capital markets reveal the complexities of economic principles such as minimum wage impacts and intertemporal choices in savings. Future discussions will delve into further aspects of capital markets.

Notes on Capital Markets and Present Value

Introduction to Factor Markets

We continue our discussion of factor markets, focusing on how capital markets impact real-world decisions. Key concepts include:

  1. Firms finance capital through a pool of savings from individuals.

  2. Individuals make choices about consumption and savings over time.

  3. Firms borrow from these savings at an interest rate i to decide on investments.

Present Value

Present value (PV) is a core concept in evaluating investments over time, which states:


PV=FV(1+i)t

where:

The key insight is: 1receivedtomorrowisworthlessthan1 received today because it can be invested.

Multiple Period Payments

For a stream of future cash flows Ct over n periods:


PV=t=1nCt(1+i)t

For example, consider receiving $10 each year for three years at a 10


PV=101.1+10(1.1)2+10(1.1)324.87

Perpetuity

A perpetuity is a constant stream of cash flows received forever, priced as:


PV=Ci

For example, if C = 10 and i = 0.1, the present value is:


PV=100.1=100

Future Value

Conversely, future value (FV) is calculated as:


FV = PV × (1 + i)t

This means if you save an amount today, it will grow over time due to interest compounding, demonstrating the critical concept of earning interest on interest.

Example of Saving

Consider two saving plans:

Plan 1 may yield a significantly higher amount due to compounding over time.

Impact of Inflation

Inflation affects the real value of money over time. The nominal interest rate i can be adjusted to find the real interest rate r:


r = i − π

where π is the inflation rate. This adjustment is crucial in decision-making:

Decision Making under Inflation

For a savings decision of $100 at a nominal interest rate of 10%, with 10% inflation, the real interest rate is zero:


FVadjusted = 100 × (1 + i) = 110

In this situation, any future gains must be assessed with respect to what they can purchase.

Investment Decisions: Net Present Value

Firms evaluate investment opportunities through net present value (NPV), calculated as:


NPV=t=0n(RtCt)(1+i)t

where Rt is the revenue received, and Ct is the costs incurred. Investments are pursued if NPV > 0.

Relation to Interest Rates

Higher interest rates decrease NPV because they increase the discount applied to future cash flows, making investments less attractive. Thus, firms may choose to hold cash rather than invest.

Opportunity Cost and Firm Decision Making

When a firm considers investment, they must consider the opportunity cost:

Human Capital Investment: The College Decision

Investing in education is akin to other investments, with costs and benefits evaluated over time.

Evaluating the College Investment

Assuming:

The opportunity costs include future earnings sacrificed alongside the immediate costs of college. The NPV of the human capital investment is influenced by interest rates, and potential earnings growth emphasizes this investment’s long-term nature.

Finally, the decision regarding college education is an investment in human capital that should be evaluated using present value principles, taking into account all costs and potential returns.

Notes on Savings and International Trade

Introduction to Savings

Savings is a critically important element of economic growth. An increase in savings leads to an increase in the capital supply, shifting the capital supply curve outward. This can be represented graphically as:


Capital Supply ↑  ⟹ Interest Rates↓

As the interest rates fall, the Net Present Value (NPV) of investments increases:


NPV=C(1+r)t

where C is cash flow, r is the interest rate, and t is the time period.

With lower interest rates, firms are incentivized to invest more, thus fostering economic growth.

Savings Rates

The current U.S. savings rate is between 3% to 5%, significantly lower than Europe and Japan’s rates of over 15%. To encourage savings, public policies include tax incentives for retirement savings, such as:

Taxation on savings, represented as:


After-tax return = r × (1 − τ)

where τ is the tax rate.

The advantage of tax-deferred savings accounts is clear: delaying taxation allows for compound interest to accrue more effectively.

Investment Strategies

Common investment options in a 401(k) include:

  1. Money Market Funds: Invest in government securities with low yields (approx. 1-3%).

  2. Bond Funds: Invest in corporate bonds, generally yielding 4% to 5%.

  3. Stock Funds: Higher risk but higher potential returns (approx. 7%).

The risk-return trade-off states that riskier investments tend to yield higher returns.

Diversification

The key recommendation is diversification. Avoid putting all your savings into your employer’s stock due to the risk of losing both your job and your investment.

Introduction to International Trade

International trade involves the exchange of goods and services across nations, consisting of exports (goods sold to other countries) and imports (goods bought from other countries). The U.S. currently has a trade deficit, notable at around $800 billion.

Trade Deficits and Surpluses

A trade deficit occurs when imports exceed exports. For example, trading one Pikachu for one Jigglypuff creates a Pikachu deficit but enhances the overall welfare of both parties involved.

Comparative Advantage

The concept of comparative advantage is vital for understanding international trade. It is based on the idea that:

For example, if the U.S. is better at producing computers and Colombia is better at producing roses, we can express this as:


Opportunity Cost of Computers in U.S. < Opportunity Cost of Computers in Colombia

Production Possibility Frontier (PPF)

The PPF illustrates the maximum possible output combinations of two goods that can be produced using available resources. For two countries, the PPF can be depicted with the following equations, assuming linearity for simplicity:


U.S. PPF: Computers = 2000 − 0.5 × Roses


Colombia PPF: Roses = 2000 − 2 × Computers

Shifts in PPF due to Trade

When trade is allowed, each country specializes in the production of the good they have a comparative advantage in, resulting in increased total output. This leads to new consumption possibilities outside the initial PPF bounds.

For example, if the U.S. only produces computers and Colombia only produces roses, the new total production could be represented with a new combined world PPF:


New World Outputs: 2000 Computers, 2000 Roses

Conclusion

International trade enhances overall efficiency and expands the production possibilities for participating countries. The trade-off is between the welfare of consumers benefiting from cheaper imports and producers who may lose jobs due to increased competition from abroad.

Notes on International Trade and Comparative Advantage

Introduction

This lecture continues the discussion of international trade, focusing on:

Comparative Advantage

Comparative advantage refers to the ability of a country to produce a good at a lower opportunity cost than another country. The key insights include:

Sources of Comparative Advantage

Comparative advantage can arise from:

  1. Factor Endowments:

    • Some countries have an abundance of certain resources (e.g., Canada’s forests for lumber).

    • Labor costs are a critical factor, explaining why textiles are often produced in countries with cheaper labor.

  2. Technology:

    • Technological advancements can create comparative advantages (e.g., Japan’s automotive industry).

    • Countries that innovate gain first-mover advantages in producing certain goods.

Welfare Implications of International Trade

Economists advocate for international trade due to its positive effects on welfare.

Consumer and Producer Surplus

  1. In a domestic market for roses:

    • Consumer Surplus (CS) before trade is determined by the area under the demand curve above the price level.

    • Producer Surplus (PS) is the area above the supply curve and below the price.

  2. When trade is introduced at a lower world price, the market adjusts:

    • Increased consumer surplus due to lower prices.

    • Reduced producer surplus.

  3. Total welfare gain can be visualized as the area gained by consumers minus the area lost by producers.

Gains from Trade

When comparing before and after trade:


Total Social Surplus = Consumer Surplus + Producer Surplus

Net Gain from Trade


Welfare Increase = (W + X + Z) − (X + Y) = Z
This shows that consumers gain more than the losses faced by producers, leading to increased overall welfare.

Trade Policy

Tariffs and Quotas

Welfare Effects of Tariffs

With tariffs:

  1. Price rises leading to reduced consumer surplus (areas A, B, C, and D lost).

  2. Producer surplus rises (area A gained).

  3. Government gains revenue from tariffs (area C).

The net welfare loss is represented by:
Deadweight Loss = B + D

Trade Wars and Policy Implications

Conclusion

Understanding international trade through the lens of comparative advantage highlights the benefits to welfare via trade, despite challenges in redistribution among different economic groups. Trade policies such as tariffs often have unintended consequences, leading to net losses in societal welfare.

Key Equations


Total Social Surplus=Consumer Surplus+Producer SurplusWelfare Increase from Trade=New Consumer SurplusOld Consumer Surplus+New Producer SurplusOld Producer Surplus

Notes on Decision Making Under Uncertainty

Introduction

The focus of this lecture is on decision making under uncertainty, a topic we have not extensively covered yet. Previous models assumed full knowledge and certainty when making decisions, however, many real-world decisions involve uncertainty. This leads us to introduce the concept of Expected Utility Theory.

Uncertainty in Decision Making

Examples of Uncertainty

1. Studying for a Final Exam:

2. Everyday Decisions:

Expected Utility Theory

Expected Utility Theory provides a way to approach decisions where outcomes are uncertain. It is grounded in the notion that what individuals care about is not the monetary outcome but the utility derived from that outcome.

Risk, Expected Value, and Expected Utility

Expected Value Calculation

The formula for expected value (EV) of a gamble can be expressed as:
EV = P(Win) × Value if Win + P(Lose) × Value if Lose

Expected Utility

Expected Utility (EU) modifies the expected value to account for individual preferences:
EU = P(Win) × U(Value if Win) + P(Lose) × U(Value if Lose)
where U(x) represents the utility function.

Diminishing Marginal Utility

Utility is often characterized by diminishing marginal utility:

Example: Coin Flip Bet

Consider a gamble where:

Analyzing the expected value:
EV = 0.5 × 125 + 0.5 × ( − 100) = 12.5
Despite having a positive expected value, we must consider expected utility.
Let’s assume the utility function is U(c)=c.
If starting consumption c0 = 100,

Calculating expected utility:
EU = 0.5 × U(225) + 0.5 × U(0) = 0.5 × 15 + 0.5 × 0 = 7.5

Given EU < U(c0), it’s rational to decline the bet, demonstrating risk aversion.

Risk Preferences

Risk Averse, Risk Neutral, Risk Loving

  1. Risk Averse: Prefers certain outcomes over risky ones. Displays diminishing marginal utility.

  2. Risk Neutral: Indifferent to risk, where expected utility equals expected value.

  3. Risk Loving: Prefers risky outcomes, possessing increasing marginal utility.

The nature of these preferences can change based on the size of the gamble relative to wealth.

Willingness to Pay for Insurance

People are willing to pay a risk premium to avoid uncertainty. The utility with and without insurance can be formulated as:


EUno insurance = P(No Accident)U(c0) + P(Accident)U(c0 − Cost of Accident)


EUinsurance = U(c0 − x)
Setting these equal allows us to solve for x, providing an understanding of risk premiums.

Applications: Insurance and Lotteries

Insurance

Insurance is driven by risk aversion, with individuals willing to pay more than expected costs to secure peace of mind against unforeseen events.

Lottery Participation

Despite the negative expected value (e.g., spending $1 with an expected payout significantly less than that), people still participate in lotteries. Theories for this behavior include:

  1. Entertainment Value: People enjoy the thrill of anticipation.

  2. Ignorance: Many underestimate the odds against them.

Conclusion

Understanding decision making under uncertainty through expected utility and associated concepts like risk aversion is crucial for both theoretical and practical applications. Future discussions could include behavioral economics, further exploring human psychology in economic decision-making.

Notes on Equity and Efficiency Trade-off

Introduction to Equity and Efficiency

Equity-Efficiency Trade-off

Social Optimum and Social Welfare Function

Social Welfare Function

Measuring Inequality

Leakage in the Redistribution Process

Sources of Leakage

Efficiency Costs of Redistribution

Conclusion

The discussions surrounding equity and efficiency illustrate the complexities economists face when attempting to create a fair system. The use of various social welfare functions provides frameworks to grapple with these trade-offs, affirming that policies must balance economic efficiency against the pursuit of equity.

Notes on Equity and Efficiency in Taxation and Redistribution

Introduction

This lecture discusses the trade-offs between equity and efficiency, particularly in relation to taxation and redistribution policies in the United States. It highlights several economic principles, including tax incidence, the elasticity of demand and supply, and the implications of different taxation systems.

Equity-Efficiency Trade-off

The equity-efficiency trade-off emphasizes the inherent tension between redistributing wealth (equity) and maintaining economic efficiency. Redistribution via taxation can generate what is known as a "leaky bucket," where some resources are lost in the process.

Leaky Bucket

This analogy illustrates inefficiencies in taxing individuals (raising money) and transferring funds (distributing money). The fundamental idea is that while aiming for fairness requires taxpayer money, the actual implementation can reduce overall economic welfare.

Taxation in the US

When analyzing taxation in the US, two key aspects emerge:

Who Bears the Taxes? (Tax Incidence)

Example: Tax on Gasoline

Let us examine a 0.50pergallontaximposedongasolinesupplierswithanoriginalpriceof1.50, resulting in:
Original Quantity = 100 billion gallons
After the tax, the price consumers pay increases to $1.80, leading to a new quantity supplied of:
New Quantity = 90 billion gallons

This yields: - Consumer Burden:
ΔPconsumers = Pnew − Pold = 1.80 − 1.50 = 0.30
- Producer Burden:
Preceived = Pnew − tax = 1.80 − 0.50 = 1.30  ⇒  ΔPproducers = 1.50 − 1.30 = 0.20
Thus, consumers bear part of the tax burden (0.30),whileproducersbear0.20.

Tax Wedge

The tax wedge is defined as the difference between what buyers pay and what sellers receive after tax:
Tax Wedge = Pnew − (Pnew − tax) = 0.50

Elasticities and Tax Incidence

The effects of a tax depend critically on the elasticities of supply and demand:

Examples of Inelastic and Elastic Demand

Income Tax vs. Consumption Tax

The ongoing debate centers on whether to tax income or consumption:

Impact on Savings

Taxing consumption fosters savings, which leads to more capital for investment and economic growth.

Transfers and Implicit Taxes

Transfers may inadvertently create disincentives for work (substitution effects) because receiving transfer payments can reduce the impact of earned income: -
Transfer = max (0, 10, 000 − Income)

Categorical Transfers and In-Kind Transfers

Categorical transfers can mitigate inefficiencies:

Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC)

The EITC represents a positive solution to the leaky bucket issue:

Effects of EITC on Labor Supply

Conclusion

In summary, the lecture highlights the importance of understanding taxation structure, tax incidence, and the distinction between income and consumption taxation. Furthermore, programs like the EITC not only provide financial assistance but also stimulate economic activity, countering the challenges of redistributing wealth efficiently.

Notes on Externalities

Introduction to Externalities

Theory of Externalities

Market Efficiency

Negative Production Externality Example

Consumption Externalities

Negative Consumption Externality Example

Government Intervention

Types of Government Responses

Corrective Taxation Example

The Role of Externalities in Policy Decisions

Real-World Applications

Limitations of the Coasian Approach

Conclusion

Notes on Externalities

Introduction to Externalities

Negative Production Externalities

Example: Steel Plant

Consider the following scenario:


Social Marginal Cost (SMC) = Private Marginal Cost (PMC) + Marginal Damage (MD)

The market equilibrium:
Demand = Marginal Willingness to Pay = Marginal Benefit

Supply = Private Marginal Cost

Welfare Maximizing Outcome

The social optimum occurs at where:
Social Marginal Benefit = Social Marginal Cost

Deadweight Loss

Deadweight loss triangle: Area where social marginal cost exceeds social marginal benefit.

Negative Consumption Externalities

Example: Smoking

Equilibrium at where:
Private Marginal Benefit = Private Marginal Cost
The social optimum reflects the external costs from smoking.

Government Intervention

Corrective Taxes

Subsidization for Positive Externalities

Current Environmental Externalities

Global Warming

Health Externalities

Conclusion on Externalities

Notes on Social Insurance and Market Failures

Introduction to Social Insurance

Social insurance refers to government-provided insurance programs that mitigate risks associated with uncertainties in life. It represents the largest category of government expenditure in the United States.

Importance of Insurance

Insurance is essential due to people’s aversion to risk and uncertainty. The private insurance market in the US, including health, auto, life, property, and casualty insurance, totals approximately $1.5 trillion annually.

Market Failures and Social Insurance

While private insurance exists, there are circumstances leading to market failures that necessitate government involvement. One key reason is information asymmetry, where different parties have varying levels of information.

Information Asymmetry

Information asymmetry can lead to market failures, particularly in insurance markets.

The Lemons Problem

George Akerlof’s (1970) "lemons problem" illustrates how information asymmetry can prevent a market from functioning optimally.

Insurance Context and Adverse Selection

In the insurance context, the information asymmetry is flipped.

Adverse Selection

Adverse selection occurs when those most likely to need insurance (i.e., higher risks) are the ones who seek it out, while healthier individuals opt out. This leads to insurers facing higher-than-expected costs.

Example of Adverse Selection

Let Ch represent expected costs for healthy individuals and Cs for sick individuals:
Ch=0.1×10,000+0.9×0=1,000Cs=0.5×10,000+0.5×0=5,000

Expected costs for an insurer that doesn’t differentiate between healthy and sick individuals can lead to losses and an eventual market failure.

Government Interventions

Various solutions exist to mitigate adverse selection in insurance markets, including:

  1. Subsidization: Providing tax credits to encourage healthy individuals to buy insurance.

  2. Mandates: Laws requiring everyone to buy health insurance (as seen with the Affordable Care Act).

  3. Direct Government Provision: Programs like Social Security, Medicare, and unemployment insurance.

Trade-offs of Solutions

Each solution comes with limitations:

Moral Hazard and Its Consequences

Moral hazard refers to the idea that individuals may undertake riskier behavior when they are insured.

Consequences of Moral Hazard

  1. Lower Efficiency: With insurance, individuals may reduce their efforts to avoid risks, leading to inefficiencies.

  2. Increased Taxation: More benefits necessitate higher taxes, which can create further disincentives for work.

Illustrative Examples

Social Security

The Social Security program offers an example of a social insurance program designed to provide income after retirement, funded by a 12.4% payroll tax.

Trade-off Evaluation

Conclusion

The government plays a crucial role in insurance markets due to the information asymmetries and adverse selection risks that plague private insurance. However, the challenge lies in designing systems that balance coverage while mitigating moral hazard effects.

Notes on Externalities

Introduction

Externalities are key to understanding market failures. The first fundamental theorem of economics states that competitive markets maximize total social welfare. However, this can be hindered by several barriers, one of which is externalities.

Definition of Externality

An externality occurs when one party’s actions affect the well-being of another party without that party’s consent. Mathematically, we can express this as:
Externality = Impact on Party A ≠ Costs/Benefits borne by Party A

Types of Externalities

Externalities can be categorized into negative and positive externalities, and can occur in both production and consumption contexts.

Negative Production Externality

A classic example involves a steel plant that produces sludge as a byproduct. This sludge harms fishermen downstream who rely on clean water for their livelihood.

Let Qs be the quantity of steel produced, and the relationship is:
Sludge produced ∝ Qs
The external cost to fishermen occurs because the steel plant does not account for the economic damage caused.

Welfare Implications

The market produces steel at the intersection of the private marginal cost (PMC) and the private marginal benefit (PMB). However, socially optimal production occurs when the social marginal cost (SMC) equals the social marginal benefit (SMB).


Social Marginal Cost = Private Marginal Cost + Marginal Damage

The optimal outcome at this point leads to overproduction, resulting in a deadweight loss, represented graphically as: - The deadweight loss triangle can be illustrated between points A, B, and C, where marginal social cost exceeds marginal social benefit.

Negative Consumption Externalities

Negative consumption externalities occur when an individual’s consumption reduces the utility of another individual without compensation.

Example: Smoking

When an individual smokes, they may affect others through secondhand smoke or increased healthcare costs.

Positive Externalities

Externalities can also be positive, whereby the actions of one party benefit others.

Example: Research and Development (R&D)

Investments in R&D not only benefit the firm but also create societal benefits due to knowledge spillovers. The social benefit is often higher than the private benefit.

For firms:
Social Marginal Benefit > Private Marginal Benefit

Firms tend to underinvest in R&D due to these spillover benefits.

Government Intervention

To address externalities, governments can implement:

Corrective Taxes

A corrective tax can internalize negative externalities by aligning private costs with social costs.

Subsidies

For positive externalities, governments can incentivize behavior that creates external benefits through subsidies.

Regulation

Another approach is regulatory mandates that directly control the level of goods produced or consumed, like production quotas on pollution.

Real-World Applications

Environmental Externalities

Addressing climate change is crucial. Current models suggest implementing a carbon tax that accurately reflects the marginal cost of carbon emissions to combat climate change.

Health Externalities

Smoking induces significant health costs on society, and measures like information campaigns, taxation on cigarettes, and illegalization of certain products could be emphasized to mitigate these externalities.

Conclusion

Understanding externalities is critical for assessing the efficiency and equity of market outcomes and formulating effective government policies for intervention.